ជម្រើសអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់
អត្ថបទនេះត្រូវការបកប្រែទៅជាភាសាខ្មែរ។ អត្ថបទនេះត្រូវបានសរសេរជាភាសាផ្សេង ដែលមិនមែនជាភាសាខ្មែរ។ បើសិនជាអត្ថបទទុកសម្រាប់អ្នកអានមកពី សហគមន៍នៃភាសាមួយនេះ វាគួរតែចែកចាយទៅវិគីភីឌាជាភាសានោះ។ សូមមើល បញ្ជីនៃគម្រោងវិគីភីឌាទាំងអស់។ សូមមើល ច្រកចូលអត្ថបទនេះ លើក្រុមទំព័រដែលត្រូវការបំណកប្រែទៅជាភាសាខ្មែរ ដើម្បីពិភាក្សា ។ ប្រសិនបើ អត្ថបទមិនត្រូវបានសរសេរជាភាសាខ្មែរឡើងវិញទេ ក្នុងរយៈពេលពីរសប្ដាហ៍ទៀត អត្ថបទនឹងត្រូវចុះបញ្ជីដើម្បីលុបចោល និង/ឬ ប្ដូរវាទៅកាន់វិគីភីឌាជាភាសាដើមរបស់វាវិញ ។ បើសិនជាលោកអ្នក គ្រាន់តែចង់បិទស្លាកទំព័រនេះត្រូវការបំណកប្រែ សូមបញ្ចូល {{អាទេស.:ត្រូវការបកប្រែ | ទំ. = ជម្រើសអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ | ភាសា = មិនស្គាល់ | ផ្ដល់យោបល់ = }} ~~~~ ទៅខាងក្រោម នៃផ្នែក នៃក្រុមទំព័រនេះត្រូវការបំណកប្រែទៅជាភាសាខ្មែរ ។ |
ជម្រើសអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ (អង់គ្លេស: Consumer choice គឺជាទ្រឹស្ដីមួយក្នុងមុខវិជ្ជាសិក្សាអំពីមីក្រូសេដ្ឋកិច្ចដែលទាក់ទងនឹងចំណង់ចំណូលចិត្តលើការទិញប្រើប្រាស់ទំនិញនិងសេវាកម្មណាមួយ to consumption expenditures and ultimately to consumer demand curves. The link between personal preferences, consumption, and the demand curve is one of the most closely studied relations in economics. Consumer choice theory is a way of analyzing how consumers may achieve equilibrium between preferences and expenditures by maximizing utility as subject to consumer budget constraints.
Preferences are the desires by each individual for the consumption of goods and services that translate into choices based on income or wealth for purchases of goods and services to be combined with the consumer's time to define consumption activities.
ការប្រើប្រាស់ត្រូវបានបំបែកចេញពីការផលិតដោយហេតុផលដោយសារតែអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ពីរផ្សេងគ្នាបានចូលរួម។ ក្នុងករណីដំបូងការប្រើប្រាស់គឺដោយបុគ្គលចម្បង; ក្នុងករណីទី 2 ផលិតករអាចបង្កើតអ្វីមួយដែលគាត់នឹងមិនប្រើប្រាស់ខ្លួនឯង។ ដូច្នេះ ការលើកទឹកចិត្ត និងសមត្ថភាពផ្សេងៗគ្នាត្រូវបានចូលរួម។
The models that make up consumer theory are used to represent prospectively observable demand patterns for an individual buyer on the hypothesis of constrained optimization.
អថេរលេចធ្លោដែលប្រើដើម្បីពន្យល់ពីអត្រាដែលទំនិញត្រូវបានទិញ (ទាមទារ) គឺជាតម្លៃក្នុងមួយឯកតានៃទំនិញនោះ តម្លៃនៃទំនិញដែលពាក់ព័ន្ធ និងទ្រព្យសម្បត្តិរបស់អ្នកប្រើប្រាស់។
The fundamental theorem of demand states that the rate of consumption falls as the price of the good rises. This is called the substitution effect. Clearly if one does not have enough money to pay the price then they cannot buy any of that item. As prices rise, consumers will substitute away from higher priced goods and services, choosing less costly alternatives. Subsequently, as the wealth of the individual rises, demand increases, shifting the demand curve higher at all rates of consumption. This is called the income effect. As wealth rises, consumers will substitute away from less costly inferior goods and services, choosing higher priced alternatives.
Model setup
កែប្រែEconomists' modern solution to the problem of mapping consumer choices is indifference curve analysis. For an individual, indifference curves and an assumption of constant prices and a fixed income in a two-good world will give the following diagram. The consumer can choose any point on or below the budget constraint line BC. This line is diagonal since it comes from the equation . In other words, the amount spent on both goods together is less than or equal to the income of the consumer. The consumer will choose the indifference curve with the highest utility that is within his budget constraint. Every point on I3 is outside his budget constraint so the best that he can do is the single point on I2 that is tangent to his budget constraint. He will purchase X* of good X and Y* of good Y.
Indifference curve analysis begins with the utility function. The utility function is treated as an index of utility.[១] All that is necessary is that the utility index change as more preferred bundles are consumed. Indifference curves are typically numbered with the number increasing as more preferred bundles are consumed. However, it is not necessary that numbers be used - any indexing system would suffice - colors for example. The advantage of numbers is that their use makes the math simpler. Numbers used to index indifference curves have no cardinal significance. For example if three indifference curves are labeled 1, 4, and 16 respectively that means nothing more than the bundles "on" indifference curve 4 are more preferred than the bundles "on" indifference curve I. The fact that the index number is a multiple of another is of no significance. For example, the bundles of good on 4 does not mean that they are four times more satisfying than those on 1. As noted they merely mean they are more satisfying.
ឥទ្ធិពលនៃប្រាក់ចំណូល និងឥទ្ធិពលតម្លៃ ដោះស្រាយជាមួយនឹងរបៀបដែលការផ្លាស់ប្តូរតម្លៃនៃទំនិញផ្លាស់ប្តូរការប្រើប្រាស់របស់ល្អ។ ទ្រឹស្ដីនៃជម្រើសអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ពិនិត្យមើលការដោះដូរ និងការសម្រេចចិត្តដែលមនុស្សធ្វើក្នុងតួនាទីរបស់ពួកគេជាអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ នៅពេលតម្លៃ និងការផ្លាស់ប្តូរប្រាក់ចំណូលរបស់ពួកគេ។
Substitution effect
កែប្រែឥទ្ធិពលជំនួសគឺជាឥទ្ធិពលដែលសង្កេតឃើញជាមួយនឹងការផ្លាស់ប្តូរតម្លៃទំនិញដែលទាក់ទង។ ឥទ្ធិពលនេះជះឥទ្ធិពលជាមូលដ្ឋានទៅលើចលនានៅតាមបណ្តោយខ្សែកោង។
These curves can be used to predict the effect of changes to the budget constraint. The graphic below shows the effect of a price increase for good Y. If the price of Y increases, the budget constraint will pivot from BC2 to BC1. Notice that because the price of X does not change, the consumer can still buy the same amount of X if he or she chooses to buy only good X. On the other hand, if the consumer chooses to buy only good Y, he or she will be able to buy less of good Y because its price has increased.
To maximize the utility with the reduced budget constraint, BC1, the consumer will re-allocate consumption to reach the highest available indifference curve which BC1 is tangent to. As shown on the diagram below, that curve is I1, and therefore the amount of good Y bought will shift from Y2 to Y1, and the amount of good X bought to shift from X2 to X1. The opposite effect will occur if the price of Y decreases causing the shift from BC2 to BC3, and I2 to I3.
ប្រសិនបើខ្សែកោងទាំងនេះត្រូវបានគ្រោងសម្រាប់តម្លៃ Y ល្អខុសៗគ្នា ខ្សែកោងតម្រូវការសម្រាប់ Y ល្អអាចត្រូវបានសាងសង់។ ដ្យាក្រាមខាងក្រោមបង្ហាញពីខ្សែកោងតម្រូវការសម្រាប់ Y ដ៏ល្អ ដោយសារតម្លៃរបស់វាប្រែប្រួល។ ជាជម្រើស ប្រសិនបើតម្លៃ Y ល្អត្រូវបានជួសជុល ហើយតម្លៃសម្រាប់ X ល្អមានភាពខុសប្លែកគ្នា ខ្សែកោងតម្រូវការសម្រាប់ X ល្អអាចត្រូវបានសាងសង់។
Income effect
កែប្រែAnother important item that can change is the money income of the consumer. The income effect is the phenomenon observed through changes in purchasing power. It reveals the change in quantity demanded brought by a change in real income (utility). Graphically, as long as the prices remain constant, changing the income will create a parallel shift of the budget constraint. Increasing the income will shift the budget constraint right since more of both can be bought, and decreasing income will shift it left.
Depending on the indifference curves, as income increases, the amount purchased of a good can either increase, decrease or stay the same. In the diagram below, good Y is a normal good since the amount purchased increased as the budget constraint shifted from BC1 to the higher income BC2. Good X is an inferior good since the amount bought decreased as the income increases.
is the change in the demand for good 1 when we change income from to , holding the price of good 1 fixed at :
Price effect as sum of substitution and income effects
កែប្រែរាល់ការផ្លាស់ប្តូរតម្លៃអាចត្រូវបានបំបែកទៅជាឥទ្ធិពលចំណូល និងឥទ្ធិពលជំនួស។ ឥទ្ធិពលតម្លៃគឺជាផលបូកនៃការជំនួស និងផលប៉ះពាល់នៃប្រាក់ចំណូល។
ឥទ្ធិពលនៃការជំនួសគឺជាការផ្លាស់ប្តូរតម្លៃដែលផ្លាស់ប្តូរជម្រាលនៃឧបសគ្គថវិកា ប៉ុន្តែទុកឱ្យអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់នៅលើខ្សែកោងព្រងើយកណ្តើយដូចគ្នា។ ម្យ៉ាងវិញទៀត វាបង្ហាញពីកញ្ចប់ប្រើប្រាស់ថ្មីរបស់អ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ បន្ទាប់ពីការផ្លាស់ប្តូរតម្លៃខណៈពេលដែលត្រូវបានផ្តល់សំណង ដើម្បីអនុញ្ញាតឱ្យអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់សប្បាយចិត្តដូចពីមុន។ ដោយឥទ្ធិពលនេះ អ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ត្រូវបានជំនួសដោយរបស់ល្អ ដែលមានតម្លៃទាបជាងប្រៀបធៀប។ នៅក្នុងរូបភាពខាងក្រោម នេះត្រូវគ្នាទៅនឹងឧបសគ្គថវិកាដែលស្រមើលស្រមៃដែលបង្ហាញថា SC មានភាពលំអៀងទៅនឹងខ្សែកោងព្រងើយកណ្តើយ I1។
If the good in question is a normal good, then the income effect from the rise in purchasing power from a price fall reinforces the substitution effect. If the good is an inferior good, then the income effect will offset in some degree the substitution effect. If the income effect for an inferior good is sufficiently strong, the consumer will buy less of the good when it becomes less expensive, a Giffen good (commonly believed to be a rarity).
In the figure, the substitution effect, , is the change in the amount demanded for when the price of good falls from to (increasing purchasing power for ) and, at the same time, the money income falls from to to keep the consumer at the same level of utility on :
The substitution effect increases the amount demanded of good from to . In the example, the income effect of the price fall in partly offsets the substitution effect as the amount demanded of goes from to . Thus, the price effect is the algebraic sum of the substitution effect and the income effect.
ការសន្មត់
កែប្រែThe behavioral assumption of consumer theory is that all consumers are rational decision makers who seek to maximize utility. More specifically, in the eyes of economists, all consumers seek to maximize a utility function subject to a budgetary constraint.[២] In other words, economists assume that consumers will always choose the "best" bundle of goods they can afford.[៣] Consumer theory is therefore based around the problem of generate refutable hypotheses about the nature of consumer demand from this behavioral postulate.[២] In order to reason from the central postulate towards a useful model of consumer choice, it is necessary to make additional assumptions about the certain preferences that consumers employ when selecting their preferred "bundle" of goods. These are relatively strict, allowing for the model to generate more useful hypotheses with regard to consumer behaviour than weaker assumptions, which would allow any empirical data to be explained in terms of stupidity, ignorance, or some other factor, and hence would not be able to generate any predictions about future demand at all.[២] For the most part, however, they represent statements which would only be contradicted if a consumer was acting in (what was widely regarded as) a strange manner.[៤] In this vein, the modern form of consumer choice theory assumes:
- Preferences are complete
- Consumer choice theory is based on the assumption that the consumer fully understands his or her own preferences, allowing for a simple but accurate comparison between any two bundles of good presented.[៣] That is to say, it is assumed that if a consumer is presented with two consumption bundles A and B each containing different combinations of n goods, the consumer can unambiguously decide if (s)he prefers A to B, B to A, or is indifferent to both.[២][៣] The few scenarios where it is possible to imagine that decision-making would be very difficult are thus placed "outside the domain of economic analysis".[៣]
- Preferences are reflexive
- Means that if A and B are in all respect identical the consumer will consider a to be at least as good as (is weakly preferred) to B.[៣] Alternatively, the axiom can be modified to read that the consumer is indifferent with regard to A and B.[៥]
- Preference are transitive
- If A is preferred to B and B is preferred to C then A must be preferred to C.
- This also means that if the consumer is indifferent between A and B and is indifferent between B and C she will be indifferent between A and C.
- This is the consistency assumption. This assumption eliminates the possibility of intersecting indifference curves.
- Preferences exhibit non-satiation
- This is the "more is always better" assumption; that in general if a consumer is offered two almost identical bundles A and B, but where B includes more of one particular good, the consumer will choose B.[៦]
- Among other things this assumption precludes circular indifference curves. Non-satiation in this sense is not a necessary but a convenient assumption. It avoids unnecessary complications in the mathematical models.
- Indifference Curves exhibit diminishing marginal rates of substitution
- This assumption assures that indifference curves are smooth and convex to the origin.
- This assumption is implicit in the last assumption.
- This assumption also set the stage for using techniques of constrained optimization. Because the shape of the curve assures that the first derivative is negative and the second is positive.
- The MRS tells how much y a person is willing to sacrifice to get one more unit of x.
- This assumption incorporates the theory of diminishing marginal utility.
- The primary reason to have these technical preferences is to replicate the properties of the real number system so the math will work.
- Goods are available in all quantities
- It is assumed that a consumer may choose to purchase any quantity of a good (s)he desires, for example, 2.6 eggs and 4.23 loaves of bread. Whilst this makes the model less precise, it is generally acknowledged to provide a useful simplification to the calculations involved in consumer choice theory, especially since consumer demand is often examined over a considerable period of time. The more spending rounds are offered, the better approximation the continuous, differentiable function is for its discrete counterpart. (Whilst the purchase of 2.6 eggs sounds impossible, an average consumption of 2.6 eggs per day over a month does not.)[៦]
ចំណាំការសន្មត់មិនធានាថាខ្សែកោងតម្រូវការនឹងមានជម្រាលអវិជ្ជមានទេ។ ខ្សែកោងចំណោតវិជ្ជមានគឺមិនស៊ីគ្នានឹងការសន្មត់ទេ។[៧]
ប្រើតម្លៃ
កែប្រែIn Marx's critique of political economy, any labor-product has a value and a use value, and if it is traded as a commodity in markets, it additionally has an exchange value, most often expressed as a money-price.[៨] Marx acknowledges that commodities being traded also have a general utility, implied by the fact that people want them, but he argues that this by itself tells us nothing about the specific character of the economy in which they are produced and sold.
Labor-leisure tradeoff
កែប្រែទ្រឹស្ដីអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់ក៏អាចត្រូវបានប្រើដើម្បីវិភាគជម្រើសរបស់អ្នកប្រើប្រាស់រវាងការលំហែ និងកម្លាំងពលកម្ម។ ការលំហែត្រូវបានចាត់ទុកថាល្អមួយ (ជារឿយៗដាក់លើអ័ក្សផ្តេក) ហើយការប្រើប្រាស់ត្រូវបានចាត់ទុកថាល្អផ្សេងទៀត។ ដោយសារអ្នកប្រើប្រាស់មានពេលវេលាកំណត់ និងខ្វះខាត គាត់ត្រូវតែធ្វើការជ្រើសរើសរវាងការលំហែ (ដែលមិនទទួលបានប្រាក់ចំណូលសម្រាប់ការប្រើប្រាស់) និងកម្លាំងពលកម្ម (ដែលរកប្រាក់ចំណូលសម្រាប់ការប្រើប្រាស់)។
The previous model of consumer choice theory is applicable with only slight modifications. First, the total amount of time that an individual has to allocate is known as his time endowment, and is often denoted as T. The amount an individual allocates to labor (denoted L) and leisure (l) is constrained by T such that:
or
A person's consumption is the amount of labor they choose multiplied by the amount they are paid per hour of labor (their wage, often denoted w). Thus, the amount that a person consumes is:
When a consumer chooses no leisure then and .
ពីគំរូនៃការដោះដូរពលកម្ម និងលំហែរកាយនេះ ការជំនួស និងផលប៉ះពាល់នៃប្រាក់ចំណូលនៃការផ្លាស់ប្តូរផ្សេងៗនៃតម្លៃដែលបណ្តាលមកពីអត្ថប្រយោជន៍សុខុមាលភាព ពន្ធលើការងារ ឬឥណទានពន្ធអាចត្រូវបានវិភាគ។
ឯកសារយោង
កែប្រែ- ↑ Silberberg & Suen 2001, ទ. 255
- ↑ ២,០ ២,១ ២,២ ២,៣ Silberberg & Suen 2001, ទទ. 252–254
- ↑ ៣,០ ៣,១ ៣,២ ៣,៣ ៣,៤ Varian 2006, ទ. 20
- ↑ Silberberg & Suen 2001, ទ. 260
- ↑ Binger & Hoffman 1998, ទទ. 109–17
- ↑ ៦,០ ៦,១ Silberberg & Suen 2001, ទទ. 256–257
- ↑ Binger & Hoffman 1998, ទទ. 141–143
- ↑ http://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/u/s.htm
- Silberberg; Suen (2001). The Structure of Economics, A Mathematical Analysis. McGraw-Hill.
- Böhm, Volker; Haller, Hans (1987). "Demand theory". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. 1. pp. 785–92.
- Hicks, John R. (1946). Value and Capital (2nd រ.រ.).
- Binger; Hoffman (1998). Microeconomics with Calculus (2nd រ.រ.). Addison Wesley. pp. 141–43.